An efficient market
is one where the undervaluing and overvaluing of shares does not occur and
therefore, abnormal profits cannot be achieved. This is because current and
past information is immediately reflected in share prices, resulting in the
efficient pricing of all shares on the market. This does not necessarily mean
that all share prices are equal to their true value. It simply means that
errors made in pricing shares are unbiased and that price deviations from the
true value are random. Another factor to consider is the efficient market
hypothesis (EMH) which explains how in an efficient market, when new
information becomes available, it is incorporated into the share price rapidly
and rationally.
However for the purposes of this blog, we are going to explore
this concept using the analogy of football with players as assets instead of
shares. So:
An efficient market
would be one where the undervaluing and overvaluing of players does not occur. For
example in an inefficient market, Ipswich Town may value their centre
midfielder Luke Hyam at £2 million. However Alex Ferguson may spot potential talent
in the player that Ipswich and other clubs have not seen and sign him for
Manchester United at this price to only discover he is actually a £10 million
player profiting abnormally from this purchase. However in an efficient market
his value would be £10 million as every piece of current information (including
potential future growth) is included in the price. When applying the efficient
market hypothesis to this example, in the situation of a match, if Luke Hyam makes
a good tackle his value may increase rapidly and rationally to £10.1 million
(rapidly as it occurs as soon as the tackle is made and rationally as it is a
relatively small factor providing only a 1% increase), however if he incurred a
potentially career threatening injury his value may decrease to £2.5 million (with
the significant price drop reflecting the potential severity of the information).
An efficient market compared to an inefficient market
does have its advantages. Firstly it encourages share buying as individuals can
be confident that they will get a fair value for their shares when buying and
selling them. In our example, managers may be reluctant to buy players if they
feel they may be paying an unfair price for them, or if they feel that when it
comes to selling the player, the price they receive may not represent their
true value. The second advantage of an efficient market is that it provides
company managers with the correct signals. Therefore managers can see exactly
the impact that the market places on their decisions. Again using our example, the
Ipswich Town management may decide to invest in a new training facility,
meaning that players can improve their skills and maximise their potential. In
an efficient market, if the market views this as positive, it may be reflected
by an increase in player values, giving signals to the management that they
have performed well. A final advantage is that efficient markets help to
allocate resources. Under allocative efficiency, ways are found to ensure that
resources are allocated where they can be most productive. If shares are priced
efficiently more funds should be allocated to those industries with the
potential for higher growth to ensure that the economy as a whole is as
efficient as possible. Linking this back to the football example, this suggests
that in an efficient market, young players with high potential should be valued
higher than those who are soon to retire, to ensure resources are allocated
efficiently across the board.
Successful analysts and investors such as Warren Buffet (whose
fund management company, Berkshire Hathaway, returned an average annual gain of
almost 20% from 1965 to date) would argue that market efficiency does not and
will never exist in reality, allowing people such as himself to continue
achieving abnormal returns. However does the concept of market efficiency have
any disadvantages for investors? I suppose the main disadvantage on the buying
side would be that it does not allow investors to exploit inefficiencies which
would significantly benefit them. For example if Ipswich Town wanted to improve
their team, they could send out their scouting network around the world to find
undervalued players and sign them, either to then sell them on for a higher
value to make a profit, or to improve their team at a lower cost as a result of
market inefficiency. In this situation, Ipswich Town would have benefitted from
the market inefficiency. However this would have come at a cost for the
exploited teams that have lost players, who in an efficient market would have
been valued correctly and therefore valued at a higher price. Linking this back
to the stock market, whilst undervalued shares in an inefficient market benefit
the buying party, they come at a cost for the selling party who is not achieving
a fair value from their sale, suggesting that efficient market provide fairness
for all.
To analyse the extent to which markets are efficient, American economist Eugene Fama (1970) devised a three tier grading system based on different types of investment approaches which produce abnormal returns. These are described in further detail and linked to the footballing example below:
1) Weak Form
Efficiency. This type of efficiency claims that all past price movements of
a stock are contained in the current share price and therefore abnormal returns
cannot be achieved from such technical analysis. When applying this to the
example within this blog, weak form efficiency would suggest that a player’s
current value is based upon all previous movements of his value and therefore
analysing how his value has changed over time to predict his future value will
not achieve abnormal profit.
2) Semi-strong Form
Efficiency. This type of efficiency claims that share prices incorporate
all of the relevant publically available information. Therefore fundamental analysis
such as analysing the economic climate nor technical analysis such as analysing
past price movement can achieve an abnormal profit as all of these factors are
incorporated into the current share price. When applied to the example this
would suggest that a player’s value fully reflects all publically available
information such as training facilities available, the coaching team and
potential future improvement, therefore suggesting that a player’s value will be efficient
and that no advantage can be gained from analysing such factors.
3) Strong Form Efficiency. This type of efficiency claims that all information, privately and publically held is incorporated into share prices. Therefore all of the people know all of the information and no abnormal returns can be made, not even from insider trading. In an efficient market a director may purchase (illegally) shares in their company if they know positive news is to be released which will result in the share price rocketing up. However in a strong form efficient economy, everybody would have this same information about the future price rise. When applying this to the footballing analogy, Mick McCarthy (Ipswich Town Manager) may discover in training that a player is actually not as good as the public believes he is as he loses the ball every time he is in possession. In an inefficient market he may try to sell this player for his higher perceived value, however in a strong from efficient economy, all information about this player’s ability will be available to the public and no abnormal returns can be achieved.
No comments:
Post a Comment